History of Banking
Banking
activities were sufficiently important in Babylonia in the second millennium
B.C. that written standards of practice were considered necessary. These
standards were part of the Code of Hammurabi? The earliest known formal laws obviously,
these primitive banking transactions were very different in many ways to their
modern-day counterparts. Deposits were not of money but of cattle,
grain or other crops and eventually precious metals. Nevertheless,
some of the basic concepts underlying toady’s banking system were present in
these ancient arrangements, however. A wide range of deposits was
accepted, loans were made, and borrowers paid interest to lenders.
Similar
banking type arrangements could also be found in ancient Egypt.
These arrangements stemmed from the requirement that grain harvests be stored
in centralized state warehouses. Depositors could use written
orders for the withdrawal of a certain quantity of grain as a means of
payment. This system worked so well that it continued to exist even
after private banks dealing in coinage and precious metals were established.
We can trace modern-day banking to practices in the Medieval Italian cities of Florence, Venice and Genoa. The Italian bankers made loans to princes, to finance wars and their lavish lifestyles, and to merchants engaged in international trade. In fact, these early banks tended to be set up by trading families as a part of their more general business activities. The Bardi and Peruzzi families were dominant in Florence in the 14th century and established branches in other parts of Europe to facilitate their trading activities. Both these banks extended substantial loans to Edward III of England to finance the 100 years’ war against France. But Edward defaulted, and the banks failed.
We can trace modern-day banking to practices in the Medieval Italian cities of Florence, Venice and Genoa. The Italian bankers made loans to princes, to finance wars and their lavish lifestyles, and to merchants engaged in international trade. In fact, these early banks tended to be set up by trading families as a part of their more general business activities. The Bardi and Peruzzi families were dominant in Florence in the 14th century and established branches in other parts of Europe to facilitate their trading activities. Both these banks extended substantial loans to Edward III of England to finance the 100 years’ war against France. But Edward defaulted, and the banks failed.
Perhaps
the most famous of the medieval Italian banks was the Medici bank, set up by
Giovanni Medici in 1397. The Medici had a long history as money
changers, but it was Giovanni who moved the business from a green-covered table
in the market place into the hall of a palace he had built for
himself. He expanded the scope of the business and established
branches of the bank as far north as London. While the Medici bank
extended the usual loans to merchants and royals, it also enjoyed the
distinction of being the main banker for the Pope. Papal business
earned higher profits for the bank than any of its other activities and was the
main driving force behind the establishment of branches in other Italian cities
and across Europe.
Much
of the international business of the medieval banks was carried out through the
use of bills of exchange. At the simplest level, this involved a
creditor providing local currency to the debtor in return for a bill stating
that a certain amount of another currency was payable at a future date often at
the next big international fair. Because of the prohibition on directly
charging interest, the connection between banking and trade was
essential. The bankers would take deposits in one city, make a loan to
someone transporting goods to another city, and then take repayment at the
destination. The repayment was usually in a different currency, so it
could easily incorporate what is essentially an interest payment, circumventing
the church prohibitions. An example shows how it worked. A Florentine
bank would lend 1000 florins in Florence requiring repayment of 40,000 pence in
three months in the banks London office. In London, the bank would then loan
out the 40,000 pence to be repaid in Florence at a rate of 36 pence per florin
in three months. In six months, the bank makes 11.1 percent? That’s an
annual rate of 23.4 percent. It is also interesting to note that a double-entry
bookkeeping system was used by these medieval bankers and that payments could
be executed purely by book transfer.
During
the 17th and 18th centuries the Dutch and British improved upon Italian banking
techniques. A key development often credited to the London goldsmiths
around this time was the adoption of fractional reserve banking. By
the middle of the 17th century, the civil war had resulted in the demise of the
goldsmith’s traditional business of making objects of gold and
silver. Forced to find a way to make a living, and have the means
to safely store precious metal, they turned to accepting deposits of precious
metals for safekeeping. The goldsmith would then issue a receipt for the
deposit. At first, these receipts circulated as form of money. But
eventually, the goldsmiths realized that, since not all of the depositors would
demand their gold and silver simultaneously, they could issue more receipts
than they had metal in their vault.
Banks
became an integral part of the US economy from the beginning of the Republic.
Five years after the Declaration of Independence, the first chartered bank was
established in Philadelphia in 1781, and by 1794, there were seventeen
more. At first, bank charters could only be obtained through an act
of legislation. But, in 1838, New York adopted the Free Banking Act, which
allowed anyone to engage in banking business as long as they met certain legal
specifications. As free banking quickly spread to other states,
problems associated with the system soon became apparent. For
example, banks incorporated under these state laws had the right to issue their
own bank notes. This led to a multiplicity of notes? Many of which
proved to be worthless in the (all too common) event of a bank
failure.
No comments:
Post a Comment